|
 |
EPW Special Article |
October 12,
2002 |
Strategy for Economic Reform in
West Bengal |
During the last two
decades West Bengal has led the rest of the country with
regard to agricultural performance and implementation of
panchayat institutions. But these developments have begun to
level out. At the same time the state has fallen behind in
other sectors – industry, higher education and state of public
finances, particularly – to an extent that is seriously
worrying. This paper reviews performance of these different
sectors, discusses possible explanatory factors, and makes a
number of suggestions for policy reforms. With regard to
industrial revival, it stresses public investment in transport
and communication, measures to improve higher education,
foster industry-university collaborations, and help
small-scale industries overcome specific market imperfections
(access to credit, technology and distribution channels). In
public finance, emphasis is placed on raising tax revenues
(especially with regard to the service sector), limiting
losses of public sector undertakings, and widening the scope
of land taxes and user fees. In the agricultural sector, the
need for a greater role of the government with regard to
biotechnology, extension services, irrigation and flood
control is emphasised, along with suggestions for encouraging
and regulating contract farming with MNCs. Finally the article
urges greater empowerment of panchayats with regard to social
service delivery and agro-business development, and
administrative reforms to enhance accountability of state
government employees.
|
Abhijit Banerjee, Pranab
Bardhan, Kaushik Basu, Mrinal Datta Chaudhuri, Maitreesh
Ghatak, Ashok Sanjay Guha, Mukul Majumdar, Dilip
Mookherjee, Debraj Ray
|
This year marks
the 25th anniversary of the advent of the Left Front government in
West Bengal, whose continued electoral success over such a long
period is undoubtedly a unique achievement. During this time the
nature of the West Bengal economy has changed much, in ways that
reflect the principal policy priorities of the Left Front. In the
rural sector the state has led much of the rest of the country, with
significant acceleration in the implementation of land reforms, and
institution of panchayati raj well in advance of the 73rd and 74th
constitutional amendments. With respect to comparisons of growth
rates in foodgrains production and farm productivity across the rest
of India, the state transformed its status from laggard in the 1970s
to star performer in the 1980s. The benefits of this have been
relatively evenly shared: the rate of decline of rural poverty since
the late 1970s has also been one of the fastest. Contrasted to these
impressive achievements in the countryside, the story is entirely
different elsewhere – in industry, higher education, or fiscal
discipline its performance relative to other Indian states has
progressively deteriorated. Fortunately there appear to be some
recent winds of change in policy direction of the Left Front,
following a recent change in political leadership, and the message
conveyed by voters in the 2001 state assembly elections.
It is an appropriate time, therefore, to review the performance
of different sectors of the West Bengal economy over the past two
decades, and distill from that some lessons for future policy
priorities. We start with the problem sectors first, where the need
for new policy initiatives is greatest – industry, higher education
and public finance. We move thereafter to discuss rural development
and governance (including decentralisation, social services, and
public administration), and argue there is a need for a fresh policy
approach in these sectors as well.
I Industry
Industrial Decline: Facts and Possible Causes
The crude facts of the last 20 years about the relative position
of West Bengal industry are nothing short of stunning. In 1980-81
West Bengal produced 9.8 per cent of the industrial output produced
in India. In 1997-98, which is the latest year for which we have the
numbers the share was 5.1 per cent, up from a nadir of 4.7 per cent
in 1995-96. Organised sector employment actually declined in West
Bengal over the period 1980-97; in particular employment in the
organised private sector went down from 10.84 lakhs all the way to
7.99 lakhs.
A similar pattern shows up when we look at foreign trade. In
1985-86 the Kolkata airport and port handled about 10 per cent of
the imports and exports from the country while in 1998-99 that
fraction was around 4 per cent. Or to take a measure of the vibrancy
of trade, in 1999-2000 the value of cheques cleared in Kolkata was
just 6 per cent of the value in Mumbai, compared to 38 per cent in
1980-81. Even in the mid-1960s West Bengal was the second most
industrialised of the larger states. By 1995-96, West Bengal was a
long way down in that list, behind Karnataka and just ahead of UP in
terms of the share of output from industry.
What makes these numbers even more striking is the fact that this
industrial meltdown happened in a period of relative peace and
political stability in the state after the turbulent 1960s and the
repressive 1970s. According to the report ‘Crime In India 1997’,
West Bengal was 30th among 32 states and union territories in terms
of the rate of IPC crime (this category includes almost all
crimes against private persons and private property) and Kolkata was
23rd among the 23 largest cities. Moreover this was a period when
incomes and therefore demand was growing: per capita gross state
domestic product grew at 2.6 per cent per annum in the 1980s and an
impressive 5 per cent in the 1990s.
Most remarkably, all this happened in a period when the
industrial growth rate in the country as a whole accelerated: the
rate of growth of industry value added was 7 per cent in the 1980s
and 6.7 per cent in 1990s compared to 5.5 per cent in the 1960s and
1970s.1 This was after all the period of the
software boom and liberalisation, the period that put Karnataka,
Andhra Pradesh, and Delhi on the industrial map of India. It would
almost seem that West Bengal opted to step off the bus just as
everyone else was getting on.
The cliché about West Bengal, the most familiar story of how
things could come to such a pass, is of course poor labour relations
– who would invest in West Bengal, when they could invest in
Maharashtra and Gujarat and buy themselves a much more docile labour
force. This is certainly not what jumps out when we turn to the
evidence on labour disputes. There were indeed a rash of strikes in
the early 1980s: according to the West Bengal Labour Commissioner
there were 78 strikes in 1980, as compared to an average of 22 per
year over the period 1990-97. The average number of man-days lost
due to strikes in the eight years from 1990 to 1997 was just below
17 lakhs. And if we leave out 1992, the one year when there was a
really big strike, the average comes down to 6 lakhs, which amounts
to less than one day per private organised sector employee in a
year. The median number is even lower at 3.2 lakhs.
It is worth putting these numbers in the context of other Indian
states. The one year for which we have data from the other states is
1996. The Indian Labour Handbook tells us that West Bengal had only
16 strikes in that year, which puts it lowest among all the major
states. These 16 strikes affected 27,000 workers, compared to 143
strikes in Tamil Nadu that affected 37,000 workers, or 129 strikes
in Gujarat affecting 1,20,000 workers.
There are a number of possible reasons why these numbers might be
misleading. Employers might have had to make huge concessions to
avoid strikes, which would of course discourage future investment.
This, however, is not what people say about industrial relations in
West Bengal. Moreover, it seems inconsistent with the ready
willingness of employers in West Bengal to declare lockouts. On
average about two crore man-days were lost each year due to lockouts
in the early 1990s. And while that number has come down since, it
was still over a crore a year at the end of the 1990s. Indeed in
1996, the one year we can make an interstate comparison, West Bengal
was the national runner-up in lockouts, with 80 lockouts according
to the Indian Labour Handbook (and 144 according to the revised
numbers issued by the state government). The government of West
Bengal numbers also tell us that the number of lockouts in any year
in the 1990s did not go below 120 when the median number of lockouts
in the other states was less than 20. In 1996 West Bengal was also
the state with the highest number of man-days lost due to lockouts.
The data on lockouts and strikes could be interpreted in a
variety of ways. One is that anticipating labour troubles, employers
were preemptively declaring lockouts, in order to put workers in a
poor bargaining position. The other is that the intrinsic
profitability of industry in West Bengal has declined for other
reasons, and the increased incidence of lockouts is a response to
that. Without a more detailed analysis it is hard to say which
hypothesis is more believable, or whether both were relevant to some
degree. But it is clear that the evidence currently available does
not provide unambiguous support to the hypothesis that labour
troubles constitute the only (or main) source of the state’s
industrial decline. And that we should seriously look for
alternative causes of declined industrial profitability.
A recent joint study by the World Bank and CII based on data from
over a thousand firms, provides some support for the view that low
profitability is the key problem in West Bengal, rather than labour
militancy. The study only reports data for the group of what they
call the poor investment climate states. West Bengal, tellingly, is
in this group, along with Kerala and UP. Value added per worker in
these states is at least 30 per cent lower compared to what the
study calls the best investment climate states (Maharashtra and
Gujarat). In an effort to assess the contribution of various factors
towards low profitability in these poor investment climate states,
the study surveyed opinions of a large number of entrepreneurs. The
entrepreneurs themselves believed that labour market rigidities,
represented by over-manning of factories, is less important in these
particular states than it is elsewhere in India (excluding the best
climate states).
While this is consistent with the evidence, cited above, on the
relative weakness of workers in West Bengal, it should not be read
as saying that the West Bengal government does not need to grapple
with the issues of industrial relations. For even according to these
numbers, firms in Maharashtra and Gujarat are much leaner than their
counterparts in West Bengal. Moreover, a part of the reason why
workers are in a weak position now may be that employers have chosen
not to make use of labour-intensive technologies – which of course
hurts both workers and employers. And the fact that workers in
West Bengal are less aggressive than they used to be after all
these years of industrial decline, is no guarantee that industrial
strife will not pick up as soon as growth revives. Finally and most
important, strikes and over-manning are not the only cost of poor
labour relations. If poor relations within the factory translate
into a lazy or opportunistic labour force, productivity will suffer.
If management has a lot of bargaining power, this might not hurt
them so much; it will be the workers who will pay the price in terms
of lower wages. Indeed we learn from the World Bank-CII report that
wages are 25 per cent lower in the poor industrial climate states
compared to the best states.
Instead of labour relations, the report goes on to cite
over-regulation, poor infrastructure and lack of skills as the most
important problems faced by the poor industrial climate states.
Over-regulation is measured in the survey by the average number of
visits to an industrial unit by a government inspector. There are
almost twice as many visits in any given year in the poor investment
climate states compared to the best states. While it is true that
these visits are often a waste of time and have the potential of
leading to corruption, it is somewhat difficult to believe that the
over-regulation itself is the key problem (except perhaps in the
case of very small firms, an issue which we will touch upon later in
this article). One suspects that the direct effect of these
regulations is dwarfed by what they represent – a government that is
regulation-happy is much less likely to cooperate effectively with
investors. Eliminating inspector visits will only help if it signals
a true commitment to investor-friendly governance.
The effects of poor infrastructure are much more palpable. A
recent study puts West Bengal 14th among Indian states in 1997-98 in
terms of an index of infrastructure, as compared with 4th position
in 1971-72.2 The index comprises (a) roads,
railways, ports, (b) irrigation, (c) electricity, (d)
telephone, (e) loan-deposit ratios of banks and (d) tax collection
of the state government. In terms of each of these individual items,
West Bengal has fallen below the national average whereas in 1964-65
it either came first or second. These facts therefore suggest
infrastructure to be a key factor explaining the decline of West
Bengal’s industrial performance relative to the rest of the country.
Poor roads delay shipments and raise shipping costs – in some
extreme cases, such as flowers and fish, delays in getting to the
market can make production entirely worthless. A case-study of a
failed mini-steel plant in Purulia in a recent report on industrial
sickness in eastern India by Sudip Choudhury and Anindya Sen reports
that each year the plant paid Rs 25-30 lakh extra for transportation
(compared to the liquidation value of the plant, Rs 81.5
lakh).3 In terms of road density per capita, West
Bengal happens to be far below the all-India average.
Electricity is another key input to production. The Choudhury-Sen
report mentions many cases of firms that became non-viable simply
because they got less than the promised amount of electricity from
WBSEB. There is some claim that now the power situation in West
Bengal is less dire, but one wonders how much of this is a result of
deindustrialisation. Moreover the power situation is reportedly much
worse outside the metropolitan district. It is also worth
emphasising that predictability of the power supply is very
important for someone who is running a business. The report on
sickness comes back time and again to the fact that investments were
made on the basis of expectations of power supply that turned out to
be over-optimistic. To avoid this, the government should draw up a
comprehensive and credible power plan for the foreseeable future,
that is then made available to investors. Indeed it may be worth
announcing very specific power supply targets by district and then
setting up a system of compensations that the government must pay
registered investors in the district in the event of failing to meet
those targets.
The third piece of infrastructure is communication. While in the
past this has been a major bottleneck, there is some reason to
believe that this will not be the case any more. For one, the
government of West Bengal clearly sees the link between investment
in data transmission technology and the hi-tech industries that it
dearly wants, and is trying to very hard to measure up in this
dimension, with numerous recent initiatives to upgrade communication
infrastructure in the state. Moreover, in the new liberalised
environment, private sector suppliers may be expected to step in to
fill in the remaining gaps and alleviate any bottlenecks that might
emerge.
This brings us to the last of the factors emphasised in the World
Bank-CII study – the supply of skills. West Bengal has fallen behind
a number of other states in terms of educating the young. In terms
of primary enrolment rates for children aged 5-9, in 1993-94 West
Bengal at 51.7 per cent was below the national average of 52.1 per
cent and its rank was 10th among the 15 major
states.4 A recent central government report puts
West Bengal third, after Sikkim and Bihar among all states in terms
of percentage of students who drop out before the secondary
level.5 However, it still compares well with most
other states in terms of the education of the current workforce. So
a skill gap, measured by average years of schooling completed by
currently working adults, cannot be the reason why West Bengal
currently has low productivity. Of course, given that current
achievements in schooling will have an impact on the workforce in
future decades, it is quite possible that West Bengal will fall
behind other states in this respect in the future.
There are, of course, many different relevant measures of labour
skill. It is possible that there may be a particular deficit in West
Bengal within the category of the highly skilled. By this we do not
just mean those with advanced degrees, but also the best carpenters,
welders and commercial artists. Exact statistics on this point are
hard to arrive at, though it is clear that now a very large fraction
of Kolkata middle class families have one or more children living
outside West Bengal. Some suggestive evidence can be gleaned from
the placement statistics of the better engineering and management
institutes, which suggests an abnormally large fraction of
graduating students tend to find employment outside the state.
Another way is to look at the data on migration. A striking fact
about the last two decades is that migration into Kolkata has slowed
very considerably, at a time when migration into Delhi and other
cities has exploded. There was a time when young men of ambition
from the south of India came to Kolkata to seek their fortunes – now
that trend has been entirely reversed. Even the marwaris, the oldest
and most well-established community of migrants into West Bengal,
are no longer looking for gold on the pavements of Kolkata.
This is of course what one might have predicted. The explanation
goes back to the very essence of big cities. Big cities exist as a
matrix, where different types of talent can be brought together. The
best welder knows that his true value will only be appreciated by
the engineer who aims to produce the highest quality. The best
engineer, in turn, wants to work for the entrepreneur who aims to
sell in the most discriminating markets and can only function if the
materials manager knows to buy the best quality materials. All these
people coalesce on the city where they are most likely to find each
other. Moreover, the ambitious measure themselves against other
people of similar ambition – it is no fun being the biggest fish in
a very small pond. Therefore they all head for the city where the
others are going. This is why big cities keep growing despite the
crowding and the cost of living – this is why people are still
moving to Mumbai and Delhi despite the fact that their commutes are
interminable and their flats are minuscule. This is also why when
the river of ambition changes course, it changes course so very
rapidly. Once Kolkata stopped being a magnet for new young talent,
the next generation of young talent decided to try their luck
elsewhere and eventually even their older brothers and sisters, now
short of young talent to work with, also decided that it was time to
move.
To make matters worse, the initial period of industrial decline
in West Bengal (which is what stopped the inflow of talent), was
followed by a long period (essentially till about 1990) when the
state government had decided to focus all its political
energies on the rural areas. This may have been the right
choice in many ways, but a combination of worsening roads,
persistent power shortages and a general feeling of decay did little
to make Kolkata an attractive venue for the young and upwardly
mobile. On top of it, there was an explosion of upper middle class
amenities (posh housing estates, clubs, discos, restaurants,
amusement parks) in all the other major cities around this time,
while in West Bengal, government ministers were telling them that
western music was ‘aposhonskriti’ (decadent culture). No wonder they
chose to leave.
Since then Kolkata has indeed become a much more middle
class-oriented city. However the experience from the US is that old
industrial cities (Cleveland, Pittsburgh, Baltimore) continue to
decline even after quality of life improves substantially (these
days Pittsburgh often gets rated as the most livable city in the
US). This is indeed what one might expect – after all for young
ambitious people deciding where to go, quality of life matters less
than being with other people like themselves.
Industrial Strategy: Options for the Future
Hi-Tech
How does the fact Kolkata has been de-skilled and is not expected
to recover any time soon, affect the way we think about industrial
policy for the coming decade? The one clear implication seems to be
that we should not pin excessive hope on knowledge-intensive
industries (or what is more popularly known as the hi-tech sector)
that will make Kolkata a Bangalore or Hyderabad overnight. These are
exactly the industries where a high level of skill matters the most,
and the benefits from clustering are the largest (what is Silicon
Valley if not the world’s largest industrial cluster?). One way out
seems to be to attract one mega-firm, which provides a hub for the
industry, as Microsoft has done for Seattle. There are encouraging
signs of late, with the recent interest shown by WIPRO and Purnendu
Chatterjee’s group (and others) in investing in Kolkata’s IT sector,
and the CII for expanding opportunities for IT training. But whether
or not the cluster takes off remains to be seen. After all West
Bengal is a late entrant among Indian states in this area, and the
competition is stiff.
Higher Education
One key aspect of comparative advantage of West Bengal in this
connection is in higher education. The state turns out a large
number of well qualified students in engineering, services, besides
the general arts and sciences, that could form the reservoir of
skilled workers in hi-tech sectors. West Bengal leads other Indian
states in the number of graduating students successfully passing the
NET qualifications for college teachers. Yet many of them seem to
leave subsequently to other states and countries looking for
suitable employment. And from all appearances the demand for quality
higher education continues to outstrip supply of seats in colleges
and universities in the state. One hears of special trains to
Bangalore run by South-Eastern Railways largely for students going
there for entrance examinations for technical courses. The high
demand for education in the state is mirrored also in the fact that
West Bengal leads India in the fraction of students who get tutored
(according to Anjini Kochar),6 and the high status
traditionally accorded to education in Bengali culture.
Indeed, the rich educational traditions of the state suggest
going one step further, by treating higher education itself as a
profitable industry where investment can be encouraged. West Bengal
is surrounded by states where the education system is in complete
disarray and where well to do parents send their children to schools
in Delhi. If West Bengal could provide good schools and colleges at
competitive prices, it could easily attract a part of that demand,
as it used to some decades ago when the brightest and the best from
eastern India would come to study in Kolkata’s schools and colleges.
To transform this into a reality, however, there has to be a sea
change in the government’s policy concerning institutions of
learning. There has to be a determined effort to create centres of
excellence, which seek to attract and retain the best talent among
teachers and researchers. This will require a sharp reversal of the
trend in the last two decades towards excessive egalitarianism and
politicisation in education. To begin with, the process of hiring of
teachers is hopelessly politicised. After that, unconditional job
security, use of criteria unrelated to merit such as political
connections and seniority in promotions and transfers imply that
teachers have no accountability. The government owns or funds most
institutions of higher education and so it can get away with
whatever it wants – just look at the sorry states that Presidency
College and Calcutta University find themselves in today, in
contrast to their past glory. There are few competitive pressures
within the system to alter this situation. On top of all this,
policies such as abolishing English as a language of instruction in
public schools at the primary level has disastrous implications for
essential skill formation in a globalised economy (although, the
government has recently announced the policy of reintroducing
English from class 1). Even countries poorer than India, such as
Ghana, have been able to attract a lot of data transcription and
operator services from the US on a subcontracting basis just by
virtue of having low wage workers who know English and have basic
computer skills. In Ghana, a country where the average income is
about $ 380 a year, the best data processors make $ 300 a month.
The best way to deal with problems in the education sector is to
provide substantially greater autonomy to existing educational
institutions by restoring the role of merit and productivity in such
institutions, and encourage the development of an entirely new set
of institutions from the private sector. Centres of excellence need
to be free of political interference, be guided by norms of
productivity (as evaluated by students and academic peers) and have
maximum flexibility with respect to tuitions, hiring, salaries,
evaluations and working conditions. The government needs to woo
investment from the private sector and from leading educational
institutions elsewhere in the country and abroad, provide setup and
facilitating assistance (in the form of land clearances, electricity
and water connections and so on, and matching grants). Most
important it needs to credibly commit to letting these institutions
operate autonomously, and foster competition for students and
teachers between new and existing institutions. If existing
institutions lose their best faculty and students to the newly
emerging ones so be it – nothing else will shake up the system
better. The entry of new institutions could be encouraged at all
levels, all the way from primary schools to high schools to colleges
and research institutes. If schools with currently high reputation
and in high demand want to open additional branches throughout
Kolkata or the state – as Delhi Public School or Springdales has
done in Delhi – there is no reason to prevent the same here. Indeed,
if Delhi schools want to open branches in Kolkata, that should be
actively encouraged as well. The role of the state should be limited
to providing scholarships to needy students, and to filling in the
gaps left by private initiative with respect to establishment of new
schools.
Yet another set of reforms pertain to bringing educational
institutions and industry closer to one another. There are promising
beginnings in this direction, with increasing emphasis on vocational
and computer training in curricular reforms, and establishment of
placement services in some existing colleges and universities. There
is even greater scope for the encouragement and establishment of
apprenticeship and adult education programmes that help small
entrepreneurs at one end, and encouraging research joint ventures
between research laboratories and hi-tech industry at the other.
Indeed, commercially viable research laboratories are potential
spin-offs from higher education. Given that there is still some
demand for careers in research among Bengali families, there could
be a future for privately funded research institutes that teach
advanced students and do research on contractual basis, in
biotechnology for instance.
Industrial Strategy: Emphasis on Small-Scale Sector
Having stressed the role of new initiatives in infrastructure and
education, we turn now to the third and perhaps most important part
of a new industrial policy – small-scale units at the lower end of
the technology spectrum. There are many reasons to accord primacy to
this part of the industrial sector. First, it is difficult to
predict whether or to what extent the high-tech sector will indeed
take-off in West Bengal. As we have mentioned earlier, this is
subject to a number of uncertainties – the state is a latecomer to
the stage, with strong competition from rival hubs in the country.
Where hi-tech clusters form and thrive is inherently difficult to
predict in advance, owing to the interdependence of location
decisions of numerous investors and skilled professionals. A
slowdown in the information technology industry has set in worldwide
since last year. It would be unwise for West Bengal to place all its
chips on this sector alone.
Second, investments in large-scale industry, such as Haldia
Petrochemicals, are also fraught with a number of risks and
uncertainties. Managing such a large joint venture between diverse
stakeholders, and raising necessary finances has already shown
significant strains. More fundamentally, the challenges of managing
such large-scale enterprises are immense. The larger the industry
(and Haldia Petrochemical is very large indeed), the more it relies
on the skills of its management – personnel management gets harder
as the manager becomes more remote from his workforce; materials
management becomes demanding as the number and amounts of purchased
materials grows, and so on. It is well established that at least in
the OECD countries, managers are paid much more in bigger firms,
which presumably reflects their heightened importance in such
enterprises. The shortage of skills (management skill in this
instance) therefore suggests large firms will suffer from poor
management. The Choudhury-Sen report makes frequent mention of poor
judgment on the part of management as one reason why particular
firms failed. It is also possible to see the preponderance of
lockouts as a result, in part, of poor personnel management – firms
had to close because they were unable to negotiate the right deals
with the workers. While one fervently hopes that the Haldia project
will indeed survive and prosper, it would not be wise to pin the
prospects for industrial revival entirely here either.
Third, and perhaps most important, even if hi-tech industry and
Haldia were to take-off, how would that ensure that the resulting
benefits spread widely, in terms of employment creation and wage
growth for semi-skilled and unskilled workers throughout the state?
There is a big market potential for West Bengal small-scale units in
the supply of cheap toys, stereos, watches and household implements
to the rest of India. This is what China supplies to the rest of the
world, and has formed the basis of their phenomenal industrial
success in the past two decades. One can add to the list of high
potential consumer products the following as well: garments,
leather, food processing, spare parts and metal-working, industries
all of which have had a long tradition in West Bengal.
The Chinese strategy is particularly attractive in being
labour-intensive and broad-based. Under what is sometimes half
ironically referred to as people’s capitalism, a lot of China’s
output is produced in relatively small firms located in small towns
and villages. The reason is that the products have been so chosen
that an entrepreneur with limited education, little capital,
semi-skilled workers and no professional management can still
achieve a high level of productivity. One also observes similar
patterns emerging in Punjab, though with a different product mix.
Indeed West Bengal also has a long tradition of successful
small-scale enterprises. The engineering workshops of Howrah were
once famous all over India, and even now the small garment producers
in Metiaburuj and elsewhere in south Bengal have a substantial
presence in garment retail stores all over India. Moreover, West
Bengal is now flush with savings waiting to be invested. It has a
higher rate of small savings net collection per capita than richer
states like Maharashtra, Gujarat, Karnataka and Andhra Pradesh. This
is no doubt in part a result of agricultural prosperity in the
state. A lot of these savings are presumably in small towns and
rural areas, where labour is especially cheap. The diversification
of agricultural production into a variety of non-food crops also
provides promise for the development of agroprocessing industries.
If West Bengal is so favourably endowed, the puzzle is why this
kind of industry has not already taken off? What are the
key constraints, and how can they be relieved?
Infrastructure and Regulation
One obvious bottleneck is the lack of quality roads. Even to go
from Metiaburuj to Howrah ‘hat’, where garments are sold, a distance
of less than 25 km, is a day’s work for the entrepreneur. If roads
were better he would only need to be away from his business for half
a day.
Power supply is another. Small entrepreneurs typically do not
have access to the schemes through which the government has tried to
provide power to industry. This is a particular problem for them
since they cannot afford the overhead cost of a captive generator.
Over-regulation is yet another problem. Small entrepreneurs are
the typical victims of corrupt factory inspectors; given the narrow
margins on which they operate, the bribes can significantly reduce
their prospects of succeeding. The prospect that an inspector could
come and shut them down soon after they spend their hard-earned
money to buy a small machine, makes them reluctant to invest in the
first place. One consequence of the fear of the regulator is that
small firms do not register themselves, making them ineligible for
formal loans and other publicly supplied inputs (such as power
supply).
The solution here is not complete deregulation but very clear,
realistic and simple guidelines in specific industries of the form –
if you have invested in this type of machine and have taken these
few other steps, the inspector has to leave you alone. This has to
be backed up by a crackdown on corrupt inspectors, necessitating the
establishment of grievance cells where complaints can be lodged and
followed up on.
Training, Technical and Marketing Assistance
Infrastructure shortages and bribes are not the only problems.
Others include the supply of skilled and semi-skilled workers, the
availability of technical and marketing assistance, and of credit
from the organised sector. The government can take an active role in
relieving each of these constraints. Even low-tech industries need
skills, in the form of primary and secondary schooling complemented
with vocational training. The experience of vocational training in
West Bengal in the past appear to be quite mixed, judging from
newspaper reports. While there are some successful institutions,
many others have foundered for the lack of adequate teaching staff
and poorly designed syllabi. Efforts to improve primary schooling
and vocational training programmes will be important here. One
solution may be to provide subsidies for apprenticeship in existing
firms, making use of the money from one of the centrally funded
yojanas for the young unemployed. Opportunities of providing
technical and marketing assistance to small-scale units should also
be provided by creating entrepreneur networks with easy access to
information and extension services provided by the government.
Getting a new business off the ground requires defining a suitable
product with a market niche either in the state or outside, in which
small town entrepreneurs need the assistance of well-informed and
well-connected intermediaries. Industrial expositions and trade
shows both in and out of the state can also provide the required
exposure, as well as access to Internet and e-commerce networks.
Credit
Finally, we come to credit, perhaps the most significant
constraint faced by small and new businesses. It is well known that
most of the savings that formal financial institutions collect in
West Bengal do not get invested in the state. Among the garment
manufacturers in Metiaburuj, it is a rare firm that has any
connection with the formal capital markets (banks, term-financing
institutions, etc). This reflects in part the fact that the
Kolkata-based banks (particularly United Bank of India and United
Commercial Bank) are now classified as weak banks, and as a result
have become extremely conservative about new lending. But perhaps
the most serious problem stems from the fact that bankers have
become extremely suspicious of borrowers in West Bengal. The
Choudhury-Sen report documents numerous instances where the bank
refused to go along with a refinancing plan by the government and/or
reputed consultants. This, in turn, reflects the experience of
banking in West Bengal in the last 30 years. Time and again,
investors have borrowed money, stripped the assets of their firm and
declared a lockout. Of course, only a fraction of the investors
actually behave in this way, but the rest get punished for it.
A number of steps need to be taken to restore sanity to the
system. First, the state government should put pressure on the
central government to revive the Kolkata-based banks. They could be
merged with other banks since privatisation is an unlikely option,
given the political resistance that this is likely to elicit from
their workers, and also the fact that no one would want to buy them
at a reasonable price. Second, the banks should be encouraged to
increase loan-deposit ratios within the state, with reasonable
allowances for bad debts that prevent excessively cautious lending
practices. Innovative schemes such as micro-credit can be encouraged
to limit default risks, and mobile banking can increase the reach of
the organised credit system to agro-businesses in rural areas.
Efforts can be made to create information networks among banks that
help them track credit histories of individual borrowers, which can
also have a remarkable effect on loan repayment incentives. Third,
the state government should institute a set of special industrial
debt tribunals, aimed at speedy disposal of the many pending
liquidation cases. These tribunals should have the power to bring
immediate criminal proceedings against those found guilty of
deliberate fraud against lenders. Fourth, the state government
should take steps to prevent firms from delaying payments to WBSEB
and other government undertakings for input purchases. The
Choudhury-Sen report documents many cases where the immediate cause
of the bankruptcy was the fact that WBSEB stopped supplying power to
these firms because they had not paid their bills for many months.
Making WBSEB tougher in terms of collecting it bills (e g,
blacklisting any company associated with someone who has a poor
record in repaying electricity bills is one way) will help avoid
getting into situations where companies owe so much to WBSEB that
their incentives get distorted.
In sum, the strategy of encouraging the small-scale sector should
be a multipronged one, aimed at alleviating the diverse constraints
in the supply of key inputs faced by such units – infrastructure,
credit, technical and marketing support. There is no need to repeat
the mistakes of traditional policies for encouraging the small-scale
sector, which were built around reservation of selected sectors and
products for such units. It is very hard for a government to know
and predict the kind of technology and firm scales that are the most
efficient for any given sector. Moreover, reservations insulate
selected units from the competition that is essential to foster the
required cost consciousness and the incentive to adapt to changes in
the marketplace and adopt new technology. Instead the emphasis
should be on maximising entry and competition in every industry.
Industrial Strategy: Summary
The broad industrial strategy proposed here is based around three
critical priorities: infrastructure, education and support for
small-scale units specialising in light manufacturing goods. Above
all, the guiding philosophy should be not to pick winners and pin
hopes on a few select sectors, and subsidise these heavily. Such a
strategy would be risky, narrowly based, expensive and subject to
the risks of political capture by resulting special interest groups.
The aim should instead be to create a facilitating environment for a
broad-based and diversified industrial sector, of the kind seen in
China or in successful east Asian countries. To make this feasible
will require a substantial shift in how the government itself
functions. It is by no means obvious how to make this happen, how to
build a governance structure that is both more responsive and more
able to stand back and allow things to happen.
II Government Finance
We turn now to discuss another leading problem area of the
state’s economy: its dire fiscal situation. The state of public
finances of the West Bengal government is currently quite alarming.
Recent newspaper reports suggest that West Bengal’s expenditure on
three heads in the current fiscal year – salaries, pensions and
interest payments on past loans – alone amounted to 110 per cent of
its total revenue. As a result the government will be borrowing not
only to fund any development programs but also to pay its wage and
pension bills (The Telegraph, May 30, 2002). West Bengal has
resorted to overdrafts with the Reserve Bank of India as many as 134
times during 2000-01. During the past year only Bihar (283), Kerala
(204), Manipur (263), Orissa (194) and Uttar Pradesh (209) had to
resort to more overdrafts. The underlying reason for West Bengal’s
financial distress is that its revenues are chronically and
increasingly falling short of operating expenditures. The revenue
deficit (i e, the gap between operating expenditures and revenues)
in West Bengal rose from 3.0 per cent to 6.7 per cent of net
state domestic product (NSDP) between 1990-91 and
1999-2000.7 In contrast, the corresponding ratio of
aggregate revenue deficits to the aggregate NSDP across all Indian
states was 0.9 per cent in 1990-91, and 2.9 per cent in 1999-2000.
Moreover, West Bengal had the single largest revenue deficit among
all states in 1999-2000. As a result of the growing revenue deficit,
the corresponding fiscal deficit (which adds loans and capital
expenditures to the revenue deficit) in West Bengal has risen from
4.9 per cent in 1990-91 to 9 per cent of NSDP in 1999-2000 (whereas
the all-state average went from 3.3 per cent to 4.8 per cent over
this period).
What do these high deficit rates imply? In the short run the
state government will have to find sources of borrowing to cover its
operating expenditures. But borrowing sources that offer reasonable
rates and are available at short notice are in limited supply. In
the past when the state government has faced a crunch it has on
occasion been forced to resort to borrowing from private sources
(such as Peerless Insurance) as an emergency measure in order to be
able to pay salaries and pensions to government employees. Since the
fiscal deficits are now higher than ever before, the possibility of
resorting to some such ‘creative’ strategies cannot be ruled out.
In the medium to long term, the brunt is eventually borne by
either new or maintenance investments in infrastructure, or the
delivery of social services – areas where spending levels are more
discretionary than the payment of salaries, pensions or interest on
past debt. These are precisely the areas in which the role of the
government in promoting growth and reducing poverty is the greatest.
For instance, owing partly to continuing fiscal stringency the
all-India average capital expenditures of state governments fell
from 3.6 per cent of gross domestic product in 1980-81, to 2.4 per
cent in 1990-91, and down to 1.8 per cent in 1999-2000. In West
Bengal this stood at 0.8 per cent in 1999-2000, and 1.3 per cent in
2000-01, well below the all-India average. The per capita plan
outlay during the Eighth Plan period (1992-97) was Rs 1,348 in West
Bengal, the lowest among all states. The all-India average per
capita plan outlay during this period was Rs 1,970, and states such
as Maharashtra, Gujarat, Karnataka, Orissa and Rajasthan had outlays
exceeding Rs 2,000 per capita.
While we do not believe that we should make a fetish of fiscal
aggregate targets, the situation in West Bengal does need
correction. How can there be an economic revival, if the state has
no money to spend to build roads, provide electricity, build schools
and extend medical facilities?
Sometimes fiscal crises serve to focus the attention of
governments to the need for deep-seated reforms, which involve an
entire government. We believe that such a time has now come. And for
this, it is necessary to begin by understanding how the state
government finances have reached their current predicament.
Let us deal first with the most common explanation: the
implementation of the recommendations of the Fifth Pay Commission.
The need to revise upward salary and pensions certainly resulted in
a steep increase in the fiscal deficit for all states: the all-India
average rose from by more than one percentage point of GDP in just
one year: from just under 3 per cent in 1998-99 to over 4 per cent
in 1999-2000, and almost 4.5 per cent in 2000-01. Yet, this is
something that affected all states, so does not serve to explain why
the West Bengal deficit is now almost twice the national average.
Having said this, it is worth noting that the level of salary and
pension payments in West Bengal has been consistently high (relative
to revenue receipts) in comparison with other states. These payments
formed 86 per cent of revenue receipts in 1998-99 (in comparison
with 78 per cent in 1990-91), whereas the corresponding figure was
lower in Orissa (85 per cent in 1998-99, 44 per cent in 1990-91),
Kerala (61 per cent and 82 per cent), Rajasthan (65 per cent and 34
per cent), Andhra Pradesh (47 per cent and 48 per cent), or Tamil
Nadu (66 per cent and 53 per cent respectively). So salaries and
pensions are high in relation to the state government’s revenues,
not just now, but a decade ago as well. In 1990-91 only Kerala had a
ratio comparable to West Bengal’s, and the former managed to bring
it down substantially by 1998-99. Of course, this could reflect
either the fact that the total amount of salaries and pensions is
too high in West Bengal compared to other states, or that revenues
are too low, or a combination of the two. This is a particularly
alarming problem since pension payments are expected to grow all
across the country, due to the increased longevity of employees. The
need for serious pension reform is urgent, as the experience of many
countries across the world clearly indicates.
Before we address the importance of revenue performance, let us
consider another possible contributing factor: the state’s debt
burden. Could they be an important cause for the higher deficits in
West Bengal relative to other states? In 1997-98, the ratio of West
Bengal state government debt to GDP was 23 per cent, which was close
to the all-India average – with many states such as Punjab, Orissa,
Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, Himachal Pradesh, Rajasthan, Kerala and Assam
recording higher levels of debt. However, this ratio has been
increasing rapidly in recent years: it rose to 26 per cent in
1998-99 and 30 per cent in 1999-2000. Similarly, the ratio of
interest payments to revenue receipts in West Bengal was 31 per cent
in 1998-99, which though high relative to the average is not out of
the range of the other states (it was 38 per cent in Punjab, 33 per
cent in Orissa, 32 per cent in Uttar Pradesh, 26 per cent in Bihar,
and 27 per cent in Rajasthan). This ratio has also been rising
quickly in West Bengal recently, approaching 40 per cent currently.
Debt service ratios of the order of 30-40 per cent are normally
considered the upper limit of the range of safety. So going by the
figures for the late 1990s, it does not appear that West Bengal’s
fiscal problems owe their origin to an excessively heavy debt burden
inherited from the past. But the debt service burdens are now
threatening to become onerous. Indeed, West Bengal has been
experiencing one of the fastest growth in outstanding debt and
interest burden among the states over the last few years. However,
this seems the consequence rather than the cause of the fiscal
crises, since (as we explain further below) the process of rising
fiscal deficits and poor revenue performance had set in much earlier
in the 1990s.
If neither expenditures nor debt constitute the main cause of
West Bengal’s persistently poor fiscal performance, there is but one
remaining possibility: a poorer record with regard to revenue
generation. This is indeed borne out by the facts. The annual rate
of growth of revenues during the decade of the 1990s in West Bengal
was 11.2 per cent, against an all-India average of 14.1 per cent. In
this respect West Bengal was singularly the worst performer amongst
the major states: even Bihar grew its revenues faster (at 11.8 per
cent per annum). And West Bengal’s performance during the 1990s was
conspicuously worse than its own in the 1980s, when its revenues
grew at an annual rate of 16.3 per cent (against an all-state
average of 15.9 per cent in that decade). Other facts can be adduced
in evidence for the revenue shortage hypothesis. In 1998-99,
own-revenue receipts formed 36 per cent of revenue expenditures in
West Bengal, in comparison with an average of 49.5 per cent for all
states, and 55.8 per cent for the group of middle income states that
West Bengal belongs to (which includes Andhra Pradesh, Kerala,
Karnataka and Tamil Nadu). As a proportion of NSDP, West Bengal’s
tax revenues have fallen from 6.43 per cent in 1986-87 to 6.04 per
cent in 1996-97; among the major states its relative position fell
from the bottom 25th percentile through most of this period to the
bottom 10 per cent in 1996-97.8 The sources of the
marked deterioration of the state’s finances relative to other
states in the19 90s therefore owes more to poor revenue
performance than any other factor.
Unfortunately, there are no easy fixes to a chronically low and
worsening revenue situation. The causes are of a structural,
long-term nature. As we explain below, West Bengal is by no means
unique with regard to the need for such reforms: the problems
afflict all other states as well, though to a lesser degree. But
many other states have already initiated long-term reform measures,
and it is imperative that West Bengal not lag behind. Andhra
Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala, Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu and Uttar
Pradesh have brought out White Papers recently documenting the
nature of the state’s finances, and outlining a medium-term plan for
improving them, something West Bengal is yet to do.
In what follows, we identify some of the main problem areas where
corrective actions are urgently needed. Taxation of Services
As with most other states, West Bengal faces a problem with
regard to taxing the service sector. It is a normal pattern of
economic development that the service sector at some stage begins to
grow relative to other sectors, and India is no exception. The ratio
of the service sector in GDP for the country as a whole rose from 36
per cent in 1985-86 to 41 per cent in the late 1990s. The service
sector accounted for 70 per cent of the growth in GDP during the
1990s, compared to about 50 per cent during the 1980s.
On the other hand, the bulk of the revenues of state governments
are accounted for by sales taxes, which are levied principally on
manufactured goods. A negligible fraction of revenues are accounted
for by taxes on the service sector. Paradoxically, their role has
been shrinking over time: the all-India average for ratio of tax
revenues accounted by tax on the service sector declined from 11.81
per cent in 1985-86, to 9.75 per cent in 1998-99. So there is a
general need to expand the base of indirect taxes to include the
service sector, i e, transport, communication, banking and financial
institutions, construction, media, education, health, and hotels and
restaurants.
How does West Bengal fare relative to other states in this
regard? The share of services in NSDP in the state is 39 per cent,
which is near the all-India average. But on the other hand, taxes on
services as a proportion of NSDP are exceptionally low in West
Bengal: it was 0.30 per cent in 1998-99, compared with 0.54 per cent
in Bihar, 0.63 per cent in Punjab, 0.64 per cent in Kerala, and at
or above 0.80 per cent in all other major states. Gujarat achieved
the highest ratio in this regard (2.29 per cent), i e, seven times
higher than West Bengal. Yet the proportion of services in NSDP in
Gujarat was 41.8 per cent, only marginally higher than West Bengal.
How does Gujarat manage to do so much better in this respect?
Understanding the answer to this question is bound to be important.
Or for that matter, why the ratio of tax revenues accounted by
services in West Bengal deteriorated so markedly in the course of
the 1990s: they fell from 0.82 per cent in 1990-91 to 0.30 per cent
by the end of the decade.
Improvement in state tax effort with regard to the service sector
is now currently receiving high priority in most states, and forms
part of the objectives of the transition to a value-added-tax (VAT)
currently in motion throughout the country. Accordingly, the
cooperation of the central government and other states will be
important for West Bengal. The transition to VAT represents a
historic opportunity to dismantle the highly inefficient and
cumbersome system of cascading taxes on the manufacturing sector at
multiple stages of production and distribution. It will also broaden
the base of indirect taxation and allow greater uniformity between
manufacturing and services on the one hand, and between different
states on the other. By reducing high levels of distortions in
costs, such a fiscal reform will undoubtedly enhance industrial
growth as well. However, for a broad-based service tax to be
feasible for state governments, a constitutional amendment will be
necessary to place services on the concurrent list. Now only a
limited set of services can be taxed by states, and the definition
of these allowed services has already been stretched to the utmost
(e g, the entertainment tax has been extended to tax hotels and
restaurants) by state governments. It will also be important to
coordinate minimum tax rates with other states, in order to prevent
a re-run of the ruinous ‘races to the bottom’ across different state
governments witnessed recently.
So the extension of indirect taxes to the service sector is not
entirely in the hands of the state government, owing to the
necessity of a constitutional amendment and harmonisation with other
states. Yet such an extension is vitally important, and especially
so for West Bengal. Current estimates of the revenue potential from
taxing different service sectors have been worked out on an
all-India basis and the highest returns appear to be realisable for
railways, land transport, pipelines, major ports, courier services,
banks (excluding basic lending and deposit services), financial
institutions, hotels and restaurants, media and education (including
tutorial colleges, professional educational institutions, and
computer schools).9
Contingent Liabilities
State government budgets do not disclose the full story behind
the state of their finances, owing to a variety of accounting
practices that enable them to circumvent central government
restrictions on their borrowing. One item missing from state budget
figures is contingent liabilities, which represent state government
guarantees for loans taken by public sector undertakings from the
market. State governments have increasingly resorted to this means
for supplementing resources of the public sector in recent years,
following discontinuation of loans to PSUs from the state banking
sector since 1993-94. In March 1997, aggregate outstanding
guarantees of 18 major states amounted to 9.1 per cent of NSDP,
though this ratio has declined now to about 6.4 per cent in
1999-2000.10 Since many of the projects of PSUs are
of doubtful financial viability, these contingent liabilities may
end up being realised in the event of repayment problems, which will
add even further to the state government deficit. The extent of
contingent liabilities of the West Bengal government is not
generally known, as it has not chosen to disclose this publicly
(unlike some other states). We have no reason to believe that the
West Bengal government’s liabilities are worse than that of other
states in this regard. However the practice of contingent liability
is of some concern precisely because of its inscrutability.
Losses of Public Sector Undertakings
Losses of PSUs also do not show up fully on state government
budgets, thus concealing the true extent of state finances.
Moreover, a recent CAG report notes with concern that accounts in
many of these PSUs are late by many years; the 2000-01 West Bengal
Economic Survey presents PSU accounts only until the year 1996-97.
In addition, less than one quarter of the losses of State
Electricity Boards actually show up in state budgets (through the
direct budgetary) subsidy even though the state government is
ultimately liable for all these losses. How does West Bengal fare in
regard to losses of the State Electricity Board?
Here, too, its financial performance is a distant outlier: in
1999-2000 there was a negative rate of return of the order of 63 per
cent to the capital invested in the West Bengal State Electricity
Board, as against an all-India average (i e, averaging across all
State Electricity Boards) of –26 per cent.11 The
SEBs of Maharashtra, Kerala and Tamil Nadu were of the order of –10
to –15 per cent. While there is some volatility in rates of return
for individual states across different years, West Bengal is
consistently the worst performer across all SEBs.
It is worthwhile, therefore, to ascertain where exactly the
causes of this dismal performance relative to other states lie. Here
the detailed data provided by the Planning Commission Report is
helpful. Costs per unit of electricity generated do not appear to be
substantially higher than other states. Nor is the average tariff,
which is also comparable. Transmission and distribution losses are
above average, but not by very much: 28 per cent in WBSEB, against
24 per cent in the others. The most important difference is in the
plant load factor, which ranged between 31 and 36 per cent in West
Bengal between 1995 and 2000, compared to an average of 66 per cent
for all the SEBs. During this same period, SEBs in southern and
western India improved their load factors from 60 per cent to
between 70 and 80 per cent. While the low plant load factor may
partly reflect industrial stagnation in the state, there is an
urgent need for a serious enquiry to study the various factors
behind this problem because it has huge consequences for state
finances.
One other dimension in which the WBSEB differs from all the rest
is the relative tariff on different classes of customers: commercial
tariffs are substantially lower, while agricultural tariffs are
higher. The pricing problem in West Bengal is therefore more severe
with respect to commercial and industrial customers, unlike many
other states where underpricing of electricity to farmers is a key
problem.
The speed of reforms in the electricity sector is another area
where West Bengal is lagging behind other states. In Orissa,
Haryana, Andhra Pradesh, Uttar Pradesh, Rajasthan and Karnataka,
state regulatory commissions have already restructured SEBs,
dividing them into separate generation and distribution units, and
issued new tariff orders. Such actions are still pending with the
West Bengal state regulatory commission. Besides rationalisation of
tariffs, initiatives to improve plant load factors at least to
parity with other states should be an important initiative in West
Bengal.
Electricity is not the only sector where PSUs have been racking
up spectacular losses. The West Bengal Economic Survey 2000-01 does
not disclose the losses of the State Transport Corporation. But it
does report that the accumulated losses up to 1996-97 of the
Calcutta Tramways Corporation was Rs 2,786 crore, of Durgapur
Projects was Rs 1,276 crore, and Durgapur Chemicals was Rs 1,670
crore. Collectively these three amount to more than the total
accumulated losses of the WBSEB till that year (which was Rs 4,897
crore). If we combine the accumulated losses of these four PSUs we
obtain a total of Rs 10,629 crore. To get a sense of what these
magnitudes mean, they outweigh the state’s own tax revenues of Rs
6,513 in 2000-01, and form over 7 per cent of the NSDP. A recent CAG
report finds that of the 11 statutory corporations and 69 public
sector companies in West Bengal (with a total investment of Rs
14,000 crore of public money), not a single one has paid a dividend
to the state government for 1999-2000, as in most years in recent
history. Commenting on the CAG report, a recent editorial in
Business Standard estimated that at 10 per cent cost of capital,
this means that on average these enterprises implicitly collect Rs
500 every month from each family in West Bengal.
Small Savings
Mobilisation
One area in
which West Bengal has progressed far beyond all other states is with
regard to mobilisation of small savings, which amounted to Rs 2,024
crore in 1995-96 and 4,690 crore in 1998-99. In contrast Uttar
Pradesh and Maharashtra mobilised between Rs 3,000-4,000 crore in
1998-99, and most other states less than Rs 2,000 crore. Yet it is
not clear what the implications of this are for the state’s
financial position. It is important to realise that these represent
a form of borrowing, rather than raising current revenues. So they
do little to alter the fundamental structural problem of revenue
shortage in the state’s financial situation. Moreover, these savings
deposits often earn above market rates of interest, besides being
eligible for various tax exemptions. So they may involve a steep
borrowing cost for the government sector as a whole. The resources
generated by the savings deposits accrue to the central government,
a large fraction of which are loaned to the state government at even
higher interest rates than the rates offered to the depositors. The
fact that the state government is indeed taking these loans (when it
can choose not to) suggests that the cost of borrowing under this
arrangement does not exceed that from alternative sources available
to it. The fact that the state is forced to borrow back these funds
is thus merely a symptom of the severe financial malaise it finds
itself in.
Other
Possibilities There are a number of other possible avenues for
improving the collection of revenues in West Bengal as for most
other states: introducing a wider range of user fees; improved
enforcement of state excise, liquor, registration of motor vehicles
and transfer of immovable properties and so on. The government has
recently attempted to raise more revenues via user fees in
education, health and water, something which needs to be encouraged.
Reforms in state bureaucracies represent another potential avenue
for effecting economies in expenditure, if there is sufficient
political will. The state government can follow the lead of certain
other states with respect to voluntary retirement schemes,
converting DA into pension benefits, not filling posts when vacated,
streamlining government departments to eliminate duplication of
functions and those tasks rendered redundant by new information
technology. Maharashtra has reacted recently to its own fiscal
crisis by freezing DA payments and converting them to pensions.
Kerala has modified the policy of leave encashment and housing
loans. An even deeper reform we will urge (in subsequent sections)
diversion of responsibilities in some sectors such as education and
health increasingly to panchayats, and reduce the size of the state
bureaucracies in those sectors gradually over time.
It may also be
worthwhile to revive suggestions for taxation of agriculture, in the
implementation of which panchayats can be actively involved. Despite
recent revisions (that came into effect from April 2002) the land
revenue still applies at a low flat rate of Rs 20 per acre above a
fairly large threshold (4 acres of irrigated land, and 6 acres of
unirrigated land). This means that the majority of middle farmers do
not pay any tax at all. Considering that they obtain significant
benefits from the government in the form of subsidised inputs, and
the substantial increase in agricultural productivity in the past
two decades, it would seem reasonable to extend the tax net to
holdings above 2 ½ acres of irrigated land. The levy could be
conditioned on the nature of cropping patterns in recent years, and
the yields realised over the last 3-5 years, with assessments
carried out periodically. A suggestion for an agricultural holdings
tax along such lines has recently been made by Indira Rajaraman and
M J Bhende,12 modifying earlier proposals advanced
by the K N Raj Committee and Amaresh Bagchi13 in
the 1970s.
The principal
stated reason that the K N Raj Committee recommendations
were not implemented anywhere in India in the 1970s was that it was
considered too cumbersome to administer, though this often masked a
lack of political acceptability mainly to the powerful lobby of rich
and middle farmers. The subsequent modifications suggested by
Bagchi, and by Rajaraman-Bhende seek to devise a version of the tax
that is administratively workable, and levied only on plots above a
certain size (two and a half acres in Bagchi’s proposal, and a
threshold to be defined by local crop surveys in the
Rajaraman-Bhende proposal). The administrative and political
feasibility of such a tax would be considerably enhanced if local
panchayats are actively involved in land assessments, and this is a
subject placed for discussion in gram sansad meetings. To encourage
the cooperation of panchayat officials, the panchayats could be
entitled to the lion’s share of the proceeds from the tax. A similar
reform in fiscal decentralisation in China occurred in 1985,
enabling local governments to keep all local revenues above a fixed
sum. The reform is widely believed to have contributed significantly
to China’s rural industrialisation, and is worth emulating in the
West Bengal context. If the panchayats become more fiscally
self-sufficient, it can reduce their need for state government
funds. Moreover we shall argue in later sections of this article
that panchayats could be given wider authority over provision of
local education and health, which can reduce the level of spending
necessary at the state government level for these services.
III Rural Development
The Left Front,
with some justice, views rural development as the one place where
their strategies have clearly paid off. The 1980s, the decade that
immediately followed the takeover by the left, saw a remarkable
renaissance in the fortunes of the average Bengali farmer. West
Bengal in the 1970s had one of the slowest growth rates of
agricultural production – whereas in the 1980s it was the fastest
growing state with growth rate of 6.5 per cent for foodgrains
production.14 There was a switch to high-yielding
varieties, a shift towards cash crops like oilseeds and vegetables,
and a substantial expansion of multiple cropping.
Remarkably,
given some of the fashionable prejudices of our times, all this was
achieved in a policy environment that quite explicitly favoured the
poorer farmers. This was the period when land ceilings were
enforced, land was redistributed to the landless and the rights of
sharecroppers were secured through Operation Barga. This was also
the period when decentralisation began. Starting in 1978, a full 15
years before the passage of the 73rd and 74th constitutional
amendments made them mandatory, West Bengal instituted a functioning
three-level system of panchayats. These panchayats have played an
active role in the implementation of the land reforms, in the
construction of roads and other local infrastructure and in helping
people take advantage of various government schemes.
The result has
been that the benefits of agricultural growth in the 1980s and 1990s
have been relatively evenly shared, which is probably not unrelated
to the fact that West Bengal has been one of the states where the
decline in poverty has been the fastest. The share of the poor went
from 73 per cent in 1973-74 – the highest across all states in the
country – to 32 per cent in 1999-2000. The remarkable continuing
political success of the Left Front must also owe something to it.
And in the one case where we have hard evidence on this point – the
case of Operation Barga – it appears that these pro-poor policies
also contributed to the acceleration in growth.
As is well
known, every silver lining must have its cloud. The cloud, in West
Bengal, is in part a consequence of its success. A large part of the
growth over the last decade was driven by the expansion of boro rice
production based on the use of high-yielding varieties and
irrigation water. By now, most places suited for boro production
have already made the switch and there is some evidence that at
least in some places the process has probably gone too far: There is
some evidence that the water table is not being replenished. More
generally, the scope for further expansion of diesel tube-wells and
canal irrigation seems to be relatively limited15
even ignoring the arsenic problem that has already become a serious
danger in several districts. The state has in fact had occasion to
buy extra water from Bihar over the last years. The switch to
high-yielding varieties can continue for a few more years, but with
60-70 per cent of acreage already converted, it will not be for
long. And it has been some years now that there have been any major
efforts on the land reforms front, reflecting, no doubt, the fact
that there are few easy options left.
It is therefore
no surprise that the growth rate has been slowing: Cereal production
rose by 28 per cent between 1985-86 and 1990-91. In the two
successive five-year periods that followed, this particular growth
rate fell to 14 per cent and then 11 per cent. Similarly the growth
rate of total agricultural output fell from a high of 15 and 16 per
cent (over the periods 1985-86 to 1990-91 and 1990-91 to 1995-96
respectively) to 9 per cent over the period 1995-96 to 2000-01.
Indeed one might expect, in the absence of further innovations,
agricultural growth in West Bengal is heading where other successful
states like Punjab and Haryana have ended up – in a plateau of close
to zero growth.
This is not to
say that there is no further scope for improvements in rice
productivity. Rice yields in West Bengal are still considerably
below those in compared to some other rice-producing states such as
Andhra Pradesh and Tamil Nadu. They are also low compared to
neighboring countries. For example, the rice yield per hectare in
West Bengal in 1999-2000 was about 2.2 tonnes, while that in China
was 4.1 tonnes, that in Indonesia was 2.9 tonnes and that in Taiwan
and Vietnam was 2.8.
China’s
pre-eminence in rice production owes in part to its success in
introducing improved varieties that are better adjusted to the local
weather and more resistant to specific pests. Many of these new
varieties were developed by private multinationals working with the
Chinese government. The Chinese government has also spearheaded
efforts to develop genetically modified varieties of a wide range of
crops: It is said that in the case of rice inserting genes from wild
rice relatives into the best performing Chinese rice hybrids is
reported to have raised yields by 20-40 per cent. It is true that
many of these new technologies are yet to be properly tested and the
associated dangers are real. Nevertheless, they have such immense
potential that it would be foolhardy to turn one’s face entirely
against them, especially given that they offer the possibility of
escaping from the current trend of growing dependence on pesticides
and chemical fertilisers. A more circumspect strategy, based on the
Chinese model, would be for the state government to strike a deal
with some multinationals in this area to develop crops suited to the
particular local environment of West Bengal. At the same time it can
appoint a panel of independent and highly respected scientists to
evaluate the risks of the new genetically modified crop varieties.
To increase crop
yields and reduce pesticide use there are also significant gains
possible from moving towards integrated pest management (IPM), which
uses information about the life cycle of crops and their pests to
determine the type and degree of crop protection needed in local
contexts.
West Bengal is
also falling behind the rest of nation in terms of water management,
perhaps under the illusion that there will always be enough water.
Panchayats need to be strongly encouraged to build and maintain
water-harvesting structures, especially in view of the continuing
deterioration in the condition of ponds all over West Bengal.
Wherever additional water resources are still available, the success
of the pilot tubewell groups programme suggests that this may be the
way of the future. Under this programme the wells are dug with
public money but then a beneficiary group of small and marginal
farmers is formed and assigned responsibility for repair and
maintenance of the tubewell. On most accounts this is working
remarkably well, in welcome contrast to the usual sight of
broken-down public tubewells all over north India. In some cases
these groups have reportedly approached the minor irrigation
department of the West Bengal government for more public tubewells
in their village, which they are prepared to maintain as well as
share in capital cost. This is an unusual and welcome instance of
local responsibility in resource mobilisation. Finally, the state
government needs to be much more concerned with flood control.
Floods have become increasingly frequent in West Bengal, with
devastating consequences for farmers. This is in part a matter of
building permanent structures but it clearly also needs better
environmental management in the uplands in collaboration with
Bangladesh and Nepal, and with possible help from international
agencies.
Unfortunately
even with all these improvements, it is not clear that the future of
West Bengal lies in growing more and more rice. For one, the demand
for West Bengal grown rice is not growing as fast as supply, with
the consequence that prices have fallen sharply in recent years.
While it is true that a part of the problem is that the central
government is not putting enough money into the public distribution
system, it is hard, given the present political climate in the
country, to imagine that this would be reversed in the near future.
In the meanwhile, the farmers face a very serious problem.
More
importantly, the hothouse-like climate that Kolkatans love to
complain about makes the state an ideal place to grow vegetable,
fruits and flowers. West Bengal already leads the country in
vegetable production and the trend is towards even more: Acreage
under vegetables grew by more than 20 per cent in the period 1995-96
to 1999-2000 to reach just over 11 lakh hectares. Prospects for
further growth in this area seem excellent. The state government,
based on the recent Policy Paper on Agriculture, seems to agree,
though it also reiterates the need to continue to pursue
self-sufficiency in food: This is mysterious – does one really
expect the rest of country to declare war on West Bengal sometime
soon? Otherwise why shouldn’t Bengal buy rice from Andhra Pradesh
and sell them vegetables?
The Policy Paper
and the McKinsey report commissioned by the state government also
seem to agree on much of what needs to be done to promote
agricultural growth – farmers need better roads to get the produce
to the market, better storage facilities and massive investment in
the agro-processing sector. The establishment of Agro-Export Zones,
proposed in the Policy Paper, is an excellent way to encourage the
processing industry, especially if firms set up in these zones can
be partially insulated from the state regulatory machinery. In
particular, it will be important to de-reserve the agro-processing
industry, now earmarked for the small-scale sector
Moreover we feel
that the government should consider schemes for encouraging
panchayats and other community organisations to get involved in the
development of local agro-processing industries, along the lines of
the sugar cooperatives in Maharashtra and the township and village
enterprises in China. In both these cases industries sponsored by
the state but run by community bodies spearheaded development in the
surrounding area and in principle, the same could happen in West
Bengal. The government could choose one or two districts with
relatively well performing local self-governing institutions (such
as the panchayat samity) and with a hinterland of better-off
agriculture could be chosen for such an experiment. These samities
could be provided some initial capital to start a collective
enterprise specialising in some area of local expertise and
potential. This may be a scheme of diversification into some cash
crop, the development of agro-processing, or marketing products of
household artisanship. Apart from paying interest on the initial
borrowed capital and a premium on an insurance fund, the samity
could be allowed to retain most of the money from this business, and
spend the proceeds on any project of its choosing. These activities
should not be subject to regulation by any ministry, apart from the
usual periodic auditing of accounts. Over time encouraging such
forms of collective initiative is likely to create incentives for
local business development. Of course some of these enterprises are
bound to fail, in which case they could draw upon an insurance fund
(to which they have contributed upfront) to weather temporary
losses. If the losses pile up and persist, the businesses should be
required to fold up. A Left Front government that emphasises
decentralisation, popular participation and the cooperative spirit
of the people, should have the courage to experiment with some local
cooperative ventures on business lines. Such ventures could generate
substantial employment opportunities without degenerating into
conduits for milking the state cow, the fate of many state-sponsored
cooperatives in the past.
Even if all
these initiatives are taken and taken successfully, however, there
are many reasons why farmers may not be in a position to extract the
full benefits of dealing with the world market. Credit and
technology are both constraints and while the state government can
help, its current financial distress will surely limit what it can
do. The more serious constraint is marketing. Consumers in the rich
countries are increasingly reluctant to eat anything that is not
guaranteed to be ‘safe’, meaning that their production has taken
place in tightly monitored environment. Lobbyists and spokespersons
from import-competing industries in these countries are always happy
to push for even tighter regulations of imports of edibles, for
obvious cynical reasons. This makes multinationals a vital
intermediary in these industries. They are the ones that can deal
with the regulatory machinery and have the requisite credibility
with the consumers for being quality and safety conscious. It is
foolhardy to think that a local firm (or a cooperative, according to
the government’s plan) will be able to compete with these firms to
get access to these markets. Just imagine what would happen to
exports from West Bengal if someone spreads the rumour that the
local firm is growing fruits on arsenic-infested land.
This, we think,
is the main reason to take the recent proposals for contract farming
seriously. Under contract farming farmers will contract with
multinationals to produce, say, pineapples on some fixed amount of
land in the current year, and the multinational will promise to buy
everything he grows at a fixed price.
The reservations
expressed by those who have opposed contract farming are certainly
worth taking seriously. For example, if the contract involves
putting the farmer’s land as collateral, there is a real risk of
farmers becoming dispossessed. While many will agree that we do not
want agricultural land becoming concentrated in the hands of a
foreign multinational, there is nevertheless a case to be made for
easing restrictions on land transfers. Land, after all, is the one
collateral that a poor farmer has: making it impossible for the
banks to seize land from defaulters, makes it harder for him to
borrow. We may therefore want to consider an alternative
arrangement, say one where the banks are allowed to seize land from
defaulters but seized land is required to be resold to a landless
labourer (from a list nominated by the panchayat) within some fixed
period.
A more serious
fear is the risk that comes from dealing with the vagaries of the
world market and the uncertainties of a new technology. In part this
can be dealt with by setting up the contract so that the price is
guaranteed at the time of planting. The government can negotiate
(and enforce) some crop insurance contracts with commercial
insurance providers, so that farmers are compensated when the crop
failure is clearly not their fault (such as when the rain fails or
when there is a pest attack that covers a large area). But even with
these measures, there is still the uncertainty that farmers face
when making specific investments in a crop (e g, scented rice) that
may lose its market beyond the next few contract rounds. For
example, Cargill – one of the model McKinsey companies – will plan
to export both aromatic and nonaromatic rice through contract
arrangements. But Cargill has faced problems elsewhere in India, and
there is no reason to believe that the same cannot happen in West
Bengal. What if Cargill shuts down its operations – where will that
leave the farmers who have already invested heavily in the special
rice varieties?
For these
reasons, and more generally to avoid ‘default’ on the part of the
MNCs, the government should require that the multinationals place a
substantial amount of money in an escrow account that is invested in
some safe asset and is available for the court or the arbitrators to
pay off the farmers in the case of a default. There may be
legitimate fears on the part of the MNCs that such escrows may be
applied indiscriminately in favour of farmers, and to avoid these it
may be possible to design schemes which permit escrow amounts to be
lowered in exchange for a history of good business dealings.
Finally, to deal
with the possibility of exploitation of contractual loopholes by
MNCs to cheat farmers, it would be important to have uniform
contracts negotiated at the gram panchayat or panchayat samiti
level. The government can then provide the panchayats with technical
assistance with the negotiation of the contract. Even after the
contract has been negotiated, there is the possibility that the
multinationals will find it convenient to reject a large part of the
produce on quality grounds. This is in part a matter of writing a
contract that is detailed enough (so many inches long, so many kilos
each, etc) and in part by appointing arbitration boards whose
recommendations are binding (in the sense that a firm that rejects
the recommendation loses its escrow money). All of this would be
easier if the multinationals involved have a name to lose and have
operations elsewhere in the country. It is similarly important to
establish the reputation of the arbitration boards by appointing
those with high proven integrity and technical competence.
The discussion
of contract farming has brought up the spectre of the Neelkuthis
reborn in some quarters. It is worth recalling that the Neelkuthis
became what they became with the active connivance of the colonial
state. If the present, avowedly pro-people, government is confident
that it has the will and the power to protect its people if and when
necessary, why would it need to close the door on very real
opportunities?
IV Governance: Social Service Delivery,
Decentralisation and Corruption
As we remarked
earlier, West Bengal has led the rest of the country with regard to
implementation of panchayati raj. A three-tier structure of
panchayat government has been functioning since 1978, elected every
five years. In West Bengal the panchayats have been actively
involved in implementing land reforms, in channeling the delivery of
farm inputs and government welfare schemes. This has enabled a
measure of accountability and popular participation, though
inevitably mixed up with the shenanigans of party politics. While
further research is necessary to ascertain their role in
agricultural growth and poverty alleviation in the West Bengal
countryside over the last two decades, on balance the expectation is
that they have played a positive role.
Nevertheless,
the extent of devolution of authority and finances to local
panchayats still remain extremely restricted. The West Bengal
panchayats have virtually no financial autonomy, either with respect
to raising financial resources of their own, or in deciding on the
allocation of funds across different local sectors. They are merely
agencies that implement projects in specific sectors that trickle
down from above. The bulk of the panchayats’ budgets consist of
centrally sponsored public works schemes (e g, those that used to be
covered by the Jawahar Rozgar Yojana). The overall scale of these
funds is determined at higher levels of government according to
specific formulae, and are typically earmarked for specific sectors:
roads, irrigation, etc. The extent of decentralisation of
decision-making to the panchayat bodies is limited to deciding where
a road project will be located, and to its implementation and
supervision. The same goes for schemes for the allocation of credit,
fertilisers, housing or old age assistance. The total quantum of the
service available for the village is determined from above, and the
role of the panchayat is limited to selecting the beneficiaries.
There is little scope for an enterprising panchayat body to decide
on the allocation of spending across different sectors. And less
still for deciding to raise resources for urgently required repairs
to a local road or canal, or to initiate a promising new project
that will benefit a large number of local residents.
In contrast,
panchayats in Kerala are automatically entitled to 40 per cent of
all state plan outlays, following a landmark decision by the Kerala
State Planning Board a few years ago. The local community then
decides the allocation of these funds across different sectors. From
various accounts, this has energised local communities in Kerala,
encouraging high levels of popular participation in the discussion
and implementation of local development priorities. In some parts
this has led to remarkably successful outcomes. Consider for
instance the Manjeri municipality in the relatively backward
district of Malappuram in north Kerala, which has not been
characterised by a traditional industrial culture. In collaboration
with some social groups and bankers, the municipal authorities
succeeded in converting it into a booming hosiery manufacturing
centre, after developing the necessary skills at the local level and
the finance.16 These and other award-winning
panchayats in Kerala dispel the common presupposition that civic
bodies in the villages and small towns of India do not have the
capability to take the leadership in developing and facilitating
skill-based small-scale and medium-scale industries. Of course there
are also many instances in Kerala where the panchayats’ attempts
have been handicapped by a lack of expertise; as a result the funds
were often spent on short-term populist or welfare projects, and
less on asset creation.
The past two
decades have also witnessed numerous experiments in democratic
decentralisation throughout low and middle income countries (e g, in
Philippines, Uganda, Brazil, Bolivia, Mexico), most of which have
been characterised by substantially greater degrees of financial
autonomy. In those countries local governments have been devolved a
substantial chunk of state revenues on a formula-bound basis. This
has resulted in a more even and equitable spread of expenditures
across regions. It has also caused major shifts in the allocation of
government spending in local areas, with greater resources devoted
to social services (roads, water and sanitation, and education). The
available evidence suggests that these shifts are in accordance with
preferences of local residents, and less with those of state
bureaucrats located in district or state capitals hundreds of miles
away. Surveys in these countries also suggest a decline in the
extent of corruption in the delivery of these social services, with
a larger fraction of services reaching the intended beneficiaries.
This brings us
to the other glaring limitation in the extent of devolution of
authority to panchayats in West Bengal: primary education and
health services, which still largely remain under various organs of
the state government. In contrast, most other developing countries
embarking on decentralised forms of governance have shifted
authority over the control and supervision of local schools and
primary health clinics to local governments. The need for a similar
reform in West Bengal has been urged by a recent report sponsored by
the West Bengal District Primary Education Project
(DPEP).17 This report points out that many other
states in India (Kerala, Rajasthan, Uttar Pradesh, Bihar and Assam)
have already initiated the transfer of authority of primary schools
to zilla or gram panchayats. In West Bengal, however, primary and
secondary schools remain under the authority of the District Primary
School Councils (DPSCs, which form part of the West Bengal Board of
Secondary Education), and various inspector bodies of the
Directorate of Education in the state government.
The DPEP project
report pinpoints the critical problem with the existing system:
limited accountability of schools owing to insufficient local
supervision and control. The problem with government schools is
partly reflected in the tendency of people sending their children to
private schools, if they can afford it. Even though the teachers are
not necessarily more qualified, particularly in rural areas, there
is less absenteeism and greater accountability. The problem is also
highlighted by the experiment with Shishu Shiksha Kendras throughout
the state. Initiated in August 1997, there are approximately 8,000
SSKs operating now. Each SSK is managed by a committee consisting of
student guardians and gram panchayat members, and appoint teachers
on a contractual basis. The Kendras are supervised by appointees of
the zilla parishad. The scheme is now being extended (since March
2001) to Madhyamik Shiksha Kendras. Another recent development
(following a West Bengal government notification in November 1999)
is that every gram sansad is to have a Village Education Council
(VEC) consisting of teachers, gram panchayat representatives,
student guardians and community representatives.
Nevertheless,
the DPEP report stresses the need to go substantially beyond these
measures. They point out that the VEC and local panchayat bodies
play no role with regard to control and supervision of the schools.
The participation of the panchayat is confined mainly to such areas
as building or extension of school infrastructure and procurement
and distribution of textbooks. The formal primary education system
is far too much in the control of uncoordinated and insulated
bureaucratic bodies or institutions captured by large teachers’
unions, often impervious to local community needs. The general
perception of respondents in the study was that the SSKs were
performing better than the formal primary schools because of greater
local supervision and monitoring of teacher performance, in spite of
the fact that the formal primary school teachers were better
qualified and much better paid. Panchayat members often could do
very little on public complaints about teacher performance in the
formal system: their protestations to the office of the District
Primary School Council and the District Inspector were hardly
attended to.
It should also
be stressed that these measures nevertheless allow a large number of
regular teachers to continue being delinquent while drawing
substantial salaries. This is neither fiscally sustainable nor
justifiable on any grounds. The public education system should not
become hostage to a group of unionised workers just because they are
politically powerful. Moreover, the problem cannot be solved by
using an alternative stream of informal, often under-qualified,
teachers. These informal teachers will soon agitate for being
regularised, thereby compounding the original problem.
Decentralisation in the field of education cannot be effective
unless and until the formal teachers are answerable to (and
dependent for at least part of their salary on) local bodies in
which parents of children are represented and have the authority to
discipline delinquent teachers. If the legal and the administrative
system are not up to the task in handling this problem, a popular
campaign to identify delinquent teachers may be the only way out.
Other problems
described by the DPEP report include lack of coordination between
the different state bodies involved in control and supervision, and
of resources available to these bodies for inspection of schools.
Teachers complained about lack of suitable infrastructure and about
being directed to ancillary duties not related to teaching (such as
routine office work, election duty, etc). Local residents complained
about teacher absenteeism and lack of accountability to students and
their guardians. All of these problems result ultimately in high
drop out rates especially between primary (Class I-V) and middle
level (Class VI-VIII) schools. In the survey carried out by the DPEP
team, enrollment rates drop from an average of 80 per cent and above
in primary schools to under 30 per cent in middle schools, with
particularly low enrollment rates (between 16 and 18 per cent) for
minorities at the latter level.
Accordingly the
following reforms suggested by the DPEP report deserve to be
implemented throughout the state. First, the VECs should be given
the principal responsibility for control and supervision of schools.
To avoid conflicts of interest, teachers should not be represented
on the VEC. Instead they can serve on school management committees
that are appointed by and report to the VEC. Second, the district
inspectors should be placed under the zilla parishads and panchayat
samitis, and their principal role should be redefined to provision
of support and training. Similarly, the DPSC should be reconstituted
as a specialised body responsible for training, evaluation and
curriculum development. Third, teachers should be absolved from
ancillary duties unrelated to teaching. Fourth, delivery of primary
education, primary health, women and child-care services need to be
coordinated in each village. Accordingly all functionaries involved
in these services at the district level and below should be placed
under the panchayats. Finally, necessary funds and training with
regard to management of schools and health clinics need to be
imparted to VEC representatives.
Such an
initiative is urgently required to carry panchayati raj to the next
stage. Such moves are already under way in other states. Given that
West Bengal was a pioneer in this area, it is imperative that it not
lag behind the rest of the country. A superior level of educational
achievement is necessary not just to secure a fundamental human
right for all citizens, but also to encourage adoption of new
technology and declines in population growth rates.
A more dynamic
role for panchayats in rural development will obviously necessitate
an increase in the level of financial resources they have discretion
over. At the moment the panchayats are largely dependent on the
state and central government for their funding. The achievements of
West Bengal relative to other states in decentralisation amount
mostly to panchayats spending other peoples’ money in a better or
more effective way. Genuine decentralisation requires a much greater
effort in mobilisation of own local-level resources, and in that
respect no state in India has yet made much progress. Given the deep
poverty of our rural population and the preponderance of
low-productivity subsistence activities, a relatively self-reliant
public finance at the local level will take many years to build. But
even under this general constraint there are many ways some local
resources can be mobilised and the culture of dependency on the
outside world in rural self-governing institutions reduced. This
also enhances accountability, as general citizens are more likely to
be vigilant if the local government officials mismanage or steal
their own money.
Following upon
and extending the recommendations by the state finance commission, a
reasonable number of taxes and fees (share of a modified
agricultural holdings tax suggested earlier, some forms of stamp
duty, amusement tax, education cess, user fees for some public
services like water or roads or ferry ghats) can be earmarked for
panchayats. Some projects may be largely funded by the state
government, but include a provision for matching funds by the
panchayat (extending the idea of the tubewell group discussed in the
previous installment). All political parties look upon the local
government as a part of a huge job-giving and patronage-distributing
machine. The electoral advantages for an incumbent government in
this respect are easy to see. But it is important to gradually shift
the focus to asset creation as a well-defined goal of the local
government (which in the long run can also be electorally
advantageous). These assets should include infra-structural assets
(such as minor irrigation or flood-control structures), human
capital assets (primary and secondary education, public health and
sanitation), and rural cooperative business development.
Increasing the
finances and authority of panchayat bodies is of course likely to
lead to corresponding abuses of power. Accordingly there is a need
for more intensive and independent monitoring and auditing of the
spending and assessment of panchayat performance, involving a
combination of citizen bodies, representatives of higher levels of
government, and NGOs. At the moment the auditing process is very
weak (and much too delayed) at best. The mandatory meetings of the
gram sabha, where major policies and items of expenditure are to be
discussed can provide some salutary checks. But in many areas the
attendance in the gram sabha meetings is rather thin and the
requisite quorum is barely managed. Kerala has had a similar
experience. It has often been alleged that panchayat funds are
mostly spent on the favorite projects of influential members of the
majority party in the area. Accordingly, members of opposition
parties and other citizens do not think their attendance in gram
sabhas serves any purpose. The perceived tyranny of the majority
party is potentially a serious problem that may undermine the
legitimacy of local democratic processes. It was for such reasons
that E M S Namboodiripad, a passionate believer in
democratic decentralisation, had originally argued for partyless
elections to panchayats. While that may not be feasible or effective
in the current context, it is important to install some
institutional mechanisms to counteract the tyranny of whichever
happens to be the local majority party. One idea is to replicate at
the panchayat level the model of the public accounts committee
system that exists in the Lok Sabha: appointment of opposition party
members can be mandated to key local committees with some measure of
veto power over large spending programmes.
Other
Administrative Reforms
In the recent
past the state government has initiated efforts to restore ‘work
culture’ in public offices. This is a difficult but important task,
involving adoption of new social norms and serious negotiations with
the powerful public employees’ unions. But such efforts are
certainly important in restoring accountability to citizens among
government employees. There is clearly a long way to go. No changes
will be effective and sustainable until some well-defined and
scrupulously enforced system of rewards and punishments is in place.
The key problem is that productivity is difficult to measure in
government offices. So simple mechanisms for linking pay to
performance are difficult to devise.
In this
connection, the Report of the Administrative Reforms Committee
appointed by the government of West Bengal (chaired by Ashok Mitra
and submitted in April 1983) had made a number of suggestions for
reorganising state administration. Many of these have never been
implemented. In employee promotion policy the committee had
suggested several steps: (1) broaden the scope of promotion in
order to give more incentives to employees now caught in low-scale
dead-end jobs; (2) create an intensive system of training and
instruction at all levels of administration to prepare candidates
for the next level of administrative responsibility; and (3)
introduce a system of quality assessment with equal weight given to
seniority, the Open Performance Report or the Annual Confidential
Report, and performance in an objective test set by an Examination
Committee in consultation with the State Public Service Commission.
We also urge the
need for well-publicised norms and rules of work discipline, agreed
upon by the employers and the employees in a particular division,
subject to approval of higher authorities. Workers regularly
violating those rules and norms should be brought to the attention
of an independent disciplinary committee vested with quasi-judicial
powers to investigate those charges and penalise those found guilty.
The penalties should include suspension, salary reductions, denial
of increments and promotions, and in some cases compulsory
retirement. The ruling party will acquire credibility in such
disciplining if a few exemplary cases of punishment of such workers
(irrespective of party affiliation) are brought to public attention.
Without that all talk of work culture will remain empty.
Other procedural
reforms could also help enhance accountability of governing
authorities. The monopoly of particular officers in
granting some permits can be reduced as far as possible, so that the
same permit or license can be issued by different offices. Bonuses
could be based on relative speed of disposal of files, subject to
minimum quality standards. The Report of the Administrative Reforms
Committee had suggested the following norms for departmental
functioning: “Where no new policy decision or new project is
involved, no file should be detained at a particular point beyond
three working days and in a department beyond a fortnight. Where it
involves an issue of policy or a new scheme, the time limit should
be three weeks. In the case of interdepartmental reference, the time
limit should be a fortnight for routine files and one month where
interdepartmental discussion is called for”. The statewide
computerisation of government offices currently under way should
allow a further reduction in these time norms.
It can hardly be
disputed that there is rampant and institutionalised corruption at
the middle and lower rungs of the government. Particular government
departments (PWD, police, excise and municipal property tax,
irrigation) and public procurement agencies should be targeted for
special investigations, and some egregious cases and punishment of
the guilty should be publicised. Corruption thrives when there is a
general perception of pervasiveness of corruption. Again, some
exemplary cases of punishment and keeping the campaign sustained
(and blind to party affiliation) are absolutely essential to make a
dent on the problem. This has to be supplemented by vigorous
auditing, performance evaluation by independent bodies, scrutiny of
large contracts and procurements, incentives to whistle-blowers,
etc. The Report of the Administrative Reforms Committee had
commented on how public complaints and grievances were handled with
“a casualness, bordering almost on cynicism” – the situation has
hardly improved since then – and suggested the setting up of Public
Grievance Cells in each department as well as in each large-sized
directorate and district administration. More important than setting
up such cells is to activate them in a time-bound fashion and
empower them or some other bodies to punish the guilty. As we have
already discussed in connection with decentralisation, mechanisms of
accountability to the local users of the public service in question
are also important. The adoption of a Freedom of Information Act
(much stronger than the toothless one proposed at the centre), and
involving non-party NGO’s in acting as watchdogs of government
performance are essential. Unlike some other states in India, party
politics in West Bengal does not give enough space to NGO’s often
depriving the local citizenry of their important performance
monitoring functions.
Corruption is
usually defined as the use of public office for private gain. A
related but wider problem that afflicts the public economy of West
Bengal is blatant privatisation of public space in various forms.
The examples around us are simply too numerous and manifest:
unauthorised occupation of space and beds in public hospitals and in
student hostels, unauthorised structures in public spaces (whether
for a union office or a place of worship), undue use by doctors of
medical equipment and publicly paid time for their private practice,
use of public schools and colleges by salaried teachers mainly to
tap potential candidates for private tuition, unauthorised
connections to public electricity lines and landfills of public
waterbodies by promoters and the real estate mafia in cahoots with
party bosses. They represent an insidious privatisation
that has become entrenched over the years. Confronting the
thick layers of related vested interests will be a politically
challenging task for any reform-minded leader.
V Conclusion
In this article
we have reviewed some of the critical areas of economic policy in
West Bengal, highlighting the most important areas of concern, and
suggesting policy directions for the future. Given that the new
chief minister has expressed serious interest in economic reform, we
hope our discussion will not only stimulate public debate but result
in action. Even in areas where reform may be difficult, it is
important to identify the key problems and recognise that they
exist. Our discussion has been motivated by this pragmatic need to
confront the facts as they are and to get the state’s economy moving
again.
Most of our
policy discussions have been guided by a widely accepted conceptual
framework in which market and state institutions are viewed as
mutually reinforcing, rather than as substitutes for one another.
Development in a market-based economy requires appropriate state
provision of infrastructure and regulatory systems, absence of
chronic deficits in public finance, widespread access to quality
education, measures to reduce poverty and creation of safety nets
for the vulnerable. With regard to industrial revival we have
accordingly stressed the role of public investment in transport and
communication, public encouragement and sponsorship of technology
and education, and specific measures to promote small scale
industries that overcome market imperfections (in credit, technology
access and distribution channels). In the government’s finances we
have urged the need for the government to raise more taxes
particularly from the service sector, and rein in its revenue
expenditures in line with revenue receipts. In agriculture we have
highlighted the role of the government with regard to biotechnology,
extension services, irrigation, flood control, and regulation of
contract farming. We have also suggested a wide range of
administrative reforms to widen and deepen the scope for
decentralisation, improve delivery of social services and enhance
accountability.
Embarking on all
these policy initiatives will surely be a challenging task in the
short run. Our hope is that they will help define the main
directions for economic policy in the medium to long term.
Considerations of administrative and political feasibility have
played an important role in our thinking: the policies we have
suggested are already being undertaken in some other Indian states
and other developing countries. We have also tried to make
suggestions that have the prospect of commanding a reasonable
consensus within the state. This may mean that we are sometimes
stating the obvious. But it is worthwhile to continue re-stating
them until they become part of a commonly accepted policy platform,
irrespective of whichever party happens to be in the government.
Address for
correspondence: bardhan@econ.Berkeley.EDU
Notes
[This paper is based on a series of articles published by the
authors in Bengali in Anandabazar Patrika over the past year.
An earlier version of Section I was published in The
Telegraph last year. The authors are grateful to Amaresh Bagchi,
Raghabendra Chattopadhyay, N J Kurian, Hiranya Mukhopadhyay, M
Govinda Rao and Mihir Rakshit for helpful discussions.]
1 Source:
World Development Report, 2000/2001, Table 11 and I J
Ahluwalia, Industrial Growth in India: Stagnation since the
Mid-Sixties (OUP, 1985) Table 2.3. 2 See Budhdhhadeb
Ghosh, Anandabazar Patrika, May 10, 2001. 3 Sudip
Choudhury and Anindya Sen, ‘Report on Industrial Sickness in Eastern
India’, mimeo, Indian Institute of Management, Kolkata, 2001.
4 P Lanjouw and M Ravallion, ‘Benefit Incidence and the
Timing of Program Capture’, Working Paper, World Bank’ 1999. The
states ahead of West Bengal were Assam (62.7 per cent), Gujarat
(60.4 per cent), Haryana (53.3 per cent), HP (79.5 per cent),
Karnataka (59.9 per cent), Kerala (83.8 per cent), Maharashtra (63.2
per cent), Punjab (71.2 per cent) and Tamil Nadu (74.6 per cent). A
recent report prepared on behalf of the WB government (The Status
of Primary Education in West Bengal by R Chattopadhyay,
S Chaudhuri, S K Ghosh, A K Sen, and V N Reddy) puts the
net enrollment rate for West Bengal at 50.7 per cent, which is
slightly lower than the above estimate. 5 See the report
in Anandabazar Patrika, June 12, 2001. 6 A
Kochar, ‘Emerging Challenges for Indian Education Policy’, mimeo,
Stanford University. 7 M Govinda Rao, ‘State Finances in
India’, report prepared for the Planning Commission, January
2002. 8 Dipankar Coondoo and others, ‘Relative Tax
Performances: Analysis for Selected States in India’, Economic
and Political Weekly, October 6, 2001, pp 3869-71. 9 M
Govinda Rao, ‘Taxing Services: Issues and Strategy’, Economic and
Political Weekly, October 20, 2001, Table 3, p 4004. 10 Ashok
Lahiri, ‘Sub-National Public Finance in India’, Economic and
Political Weekly, April 29, 2000, 1539-52. 11 Planning
Commission Report on State Electricity Boards, 2001 12 ‘A
Land-Based Agricultural Presumptive Tax Designed for Levy by
Panchayats’, Economic and Political Weekly, April 4, 1998, pp
765-78. 13 ‘Agricultural Holdings Tax: A Modified Scheme’,
Economic and Political Weekly, September 23, 1978, pp
1631-48. 14 Anamitra Saha and Madhura Swaminathan, ‘Agricultural
Growth in West Bengal in the 1980s: A Disaggregation by Districts
and Crops’, Economic and Political Weekly, March 26,
1994, pp A2-A11. 15 See for example, Vikas Rawal: ‘Expansion of
Irrigation in West Bengal: Mid-1970s to Mid-1990s’, Economic and
Political Weekly, October 20, 2001. 16 M K Das, ‘Kerala’s
Decentralised Planning’, Economic and Political Weekly,
December 2, 2000. 17 ‘The Role of Panchayat in Primary Education
in West Bengal’, by a project team headed by Raghabendra
Chattopadhyay and V N Reddy, August 2001.
| |
 |
|